Chapter 7: Quality control
In Chapter 7 we explore:
Quality control spectrum
Codes of conduct
Characteristics
Weaknesses
Strengths
A carrot rather than a stick approach
Moral suasion
Pre-emption of external and obligatory regulation
Elements of success
Eco-labels
Industry incentives for participation
Anatomy of ecolabelling schemes
Attributes of success.
Green globe 21
Affiliated status
Benchmarked status
Certified status
Membership patterns
Critique
Specialized ecolabels
Blue Flag
‘Green Hotels Association
Commited to Green Foundation
TUI environmental monitoring of contracted hotels
Weaknesses of tourism ecolabels
The Mohonk Agreement
Awards
British Airways Tourism for Tomorrow Awards
World Legacy Awards
On the ground: toward sustainable tourism certification in
Costa Rica.
Upon completion of this chapter, YOU, the reader, should be
able to:
·
Explain the role and
importance of quality control in attaining environmental and sociocultural
sustainability within the conventional tourism industry
·
Describe and differentiate
the various levels of quality control in tourism
·
Discuss and compare the
positive and negative aspects of codes of conduct, awards and
certification-based ecolabel programmers in sustainable tourism
·
Explain the difference and
relation between Certification and Accreditation
·
Present and assess examples
of best practice quality control in sustainable tourism especially at the
certification and accreditation level and, finally,
·
Assess the factors that
increase the likelihood that a quality control initiative in tourism will
succeed as a mechanism for fostering sustainable tourism development.
To be able to do all those marvelous things… you need to
read the chapter. Right now, I’m going offer you an alternative viewpoint on
the last bullet point, suggesting that paradoxically these mechanisms actually
may NOT foster sustainable tourism, by
giving you another Culhane relational summary of Weaver’s main chapter
points, starting with…
Section 7.1: INTRODUCTION in which I introduce you to my
belief in
“The Dangers of Differentiating the Product”
See, here’s the thing:
Weaver says on page 110: “The conventional tourism industry,
by and large, has formally recognized through its constituent organizations a
desire to purse an environmentally and socioculturally sustainable path of
development. The actual extent of this pursuit, however, is a matter of debate,
given that most initiatives appear to be of the superficial or ‘weak variety
and/or are exemplified by a relatively small number of industry leaders, such
as British Airways and the Aspen Ski Company.
However far the actual effort within the industry has proceeded, a
critical component in achieving sustainability is the implementation of and
adherence to quality control mechanism that guide the process and demonstrate
adherence to relevant principles and practices, thereby differentiating the product from those not adhering to these mechanisms.”
Sounds good right? All you have to do to be a green
millionaire or, in a more competitive landscape, stay in business as a green business, is paradoxically hope nobody else adopts the sustainable
practices you say you believe in.
And this is going to lead to social and environmental
justice exactly how?
Take a look at this diagram based on Rogers curve of the diffusion
of innovations and Maloney’s 16% rule.
What happens if we apply it to
what I call “the dangers of differentiating the product”?
The diagram assumes
that in every population roughly 2.5% of the people are innovators and another
13.5% are visionaries. Together they
make up the creators and early adopters of any new technology or idea. In the Harry Potter world these are the folks
who make up Hogwarts. The rest of us are
the muggles: 34% the pragmatic early
majority, 34% the conservative late majority, and the remaining 16% the
skeptical inactive late mass. We
ridicule people like this, don’t we? The
one’s who “just don’t get it?” If we map
the Plog tourist profile curve onto the diffusion innovation curve we can even unpack
our own biased assumptions that the innovative 16% are the allocentric
tourists, ideal for the evolving “green market” while half of the pragmatic
early majority are midcentric, and the rest tend toward an ever more
conservative psychocentric profile. Of
course it isn’t that simple. But those
are the general trends. As Human beings,
it seems, we just can’t help judging each other and trying to pigeonhole one
another into bell curve distributed groups, just like we did in school, with A students on one side and F students on
the other. But that isn’t what disturbs
me about the human desire to differentiate people and products in the green
tourism industry.
What I find dangerous about the trend toward green product differentiation described by Weaver is that it ignores the underlying paradox of green marketing which, in turn reveals the famous fundamental internal contradictions of late stage capitalism.
What I find dangerous about the trend toward green product differentiation described by Weaver is that it ignores the underlying paradox of green marketing which, in turn reveals the famous fundamental internal contradictions of late stage capitalism.
The paradox is illustrated nicely by the diagram. Note that on the left side of the chasm
the “Psychology of Influence” is
“Scarcity”. The Zero sum game. We do
things because they make us ‘special’, because they make us STAND OUT from the maddening
crowd. Of muggles.
On the right side of the chasm the psychology
of influence is “Social Proof” where we do something good not because it makes
us special, but because everybody is doing it as part of the ethics of our culture.
The 16% rule chasm lies between. Maloney’s rule states: “Once you have
reached 16% adoption of any innovation you must change your messaging and media
strategy from one based on scarcity to one based on social proof in order to
accelerate through the chasm to the tipping point.”
The tipping point in our case would be the moment when being sustainable becomes so trendy you couldn’t imagine NOT being sustainable. Oh the shame!
The tipping point in our case would be the moment when being sustainable becomes so trendy you couldn’t imagine NOT being sustainable. Oh the shame!
And here’s the problem (you can see it can’t you?): If
sustainable tourism operators try to differentiate their product by
providing the only (or one of the few)
tourism destinations that are eco-friendly or socially just, the scarcity
business model depends for its success on their keeping the other destinations
exploitative and polluted.
I saw this first hand
in the Dominican Republic.
My students and I from Mercy College went to the DR to do
Voluntourism work and stayed the first couple of days with the family of one of
our students in the economically depressed area of Boca Chica not all that far
from the airport. My little kids and
their mother were with me and we all decided to go to the beach. The public beach, the beach free to everyone,
however, was filled with trash both on
the sand and in the water, the view was spoiled by a downwind cement factory on
a pier over the water belching smoke in the distance and the unregulated competing
restaurants were blaring distorted music and eardrum shattering levels while
vendors hawking trinkets disturbed every minute of tranquility we had. At a certain point my children’s mother was
fed up and wanted to go home, but I encouraged her to bring the kids and walk
up the beach about 15 minutes around a curve.
On the other side we found a gated fence and a series of beautiful
resorts with clean soft sand, lots of coconut trees, beautiful views of clear
blue seas, beautiful architecture and tranquility. Because my children’s mother is German and
my children look European and not local, the beach guards did not stop us from
simply waltzing in. The contrast was
immediate and amazing. It was clear that
the beauty and tranquility and cleanliness of these sections of beach were what
enabled the resorts to offer a
“differentiated product” for which guests pay a premium. The rest of
Boca Chica, by contrast, is a nightmare, and going to the public beaches for
free is not something a tourist would ever want to do. One wonders if this doesn’t create a perverse
incentive to tour operators who have influence over government policy to
deliberately keep the public beaches in a state of degradation.
When the messaging and media strategy is based on scarcity
there is no incentive to clean up or green up the entire industry. Powerful
market forces will keep the few resorts doing good things on the left of Maloney’s
chasm and in fact it will be in the best
interest of the tour operators to see the other areas destroyed. For example, if
one of your selling points is the availability of wild sea turtles and dolphins
at your resort, you may be happy to allow coral destruction and poaching on the
other side of the island, driving the remaining wildlife to you and reducing
competition. It may behoove you to have the only remaining stands of primary
rainforest or mountain gorillas so you can charge top dollar to see them. It was ironic to me when I went to Gombe
stream resort in Tanzania to work with the Jane Goodall Institute that they
were cooking the tourists expensive meals on charcoal from forest trees cut
down in neighboring forests, furthering the extinction of chimps in those
areas. The Tanzanian tourist authority
charges several hundred dollars to see their chimps “in the wild”; this fee can
only be commanded when there are no wild chimps left to encounter when hiking
in adjacent forests; given that Gombe is now a tiny island of fragment forest
in a sea of ever increasing agricultural destruction, it was hard for me to get
the sense that it wasn’t turning into essentially a very large zoo.
So what would happen to “green tourism” if we actually
crossed the chasm and went from a scarcity model to a “social proof”
model? If EVERYBODY had a sustainable
eco-friendly and socially just experience to offer tourists, which you would
imagine is the goal of the sustainable tourism movement, would there be any
product to differentiate? Would there be anything to offer to distinguish your
operation from your neighbor? What added value could a tour destination offer
if and when the world is healed again and wildlife and beauty and clean
renewable energy and recycling and health are available everywhere? For me this
is the million dollar question for sustainable tourism. How do we “change our messaging and media
strategy from one based on scarcity to one based on social proof in order to
accelerate through the chasm to the tipping point”
The issue of Quality Control is brought up in section 7.2 of the chapter where we learn that companies usually require “mechanisms that indicate, through external recognition or other means, the quality and credibility of a company’s sustainability performance” and that there is a is a spectrum of quality control mechanisms ranging from those that are internal or voluntary to those that are increasingly external and obligatory. We learn that the pursuit of sustainable tourism is often “hindered by the fact that external enforcement of regulations and laws are “seldom promulgated as part of an integrated and formal programme of achieving sustainable tourism outcomes in cooperation with tourism stakeolder groups. These laws therefore may be either excessive or inadequate.”
The issue of Quality Control is brought up in section 7.2 of the chapter where we learn that companies usually require “mechanisms that indicate, through external recognition or other means, the quality and credibility of a company’s sustainability performance” and that there is a is a spectrum of quality control mechanisms ranging from those that are internal or voluntary to those that are increasingly external and obligatory. We learn that the pursuit of sustainable tourism is often “hindered by the fact that external enforcement of regulations and laws are “seldom promulgated as part of an integrated and formal programme of achieving sustainable tourism outcomes in cooperation with tourism stakeolder groups. These laws therefore may be either excessive or inadequate.”
What isn’t addressed is WHY they may be inadequate from a
structural perspective. What is keeping
external enforcement so lax? We usually
think of Codes of conduct, which Weaver says are often called “codes of ethics”
for sustainable tourism, as falling into three categories, those intended for
tourists, for host communities, or the tourism industry (page 111). Codes that are intended for tourists can be
drivers of real change, since what Weaver calls “deep green tourists” create
demand for better practices by host communities and the tourism industry. But codes intended for host communities and
industry operators are “almost always
based on the principle of voluntary adherence and predicated on the principle
of self-regulation so that the member company is responsible for ensuring its
own compliance”. This is described as “leaving the fox watching the hen house”
with one of the weaknesses described as being the tendency for there to be “unscrupulous
companies putting their voluntary adherence to vague directives of the
APECT/PATA codes, giving them a certified “quality tourism product” , giving false
evidence of their green credentials, even though all they sometimes do is
restate what is required by law”. The cynical perspective Weaver talks about
comes from a “lack of evidence that existing codes of conduct are being
monitored and enforced” while the principles themselves are “not intended to
create new legal liabilities, expand existing rights or obligations, waive
legal defenses or otherwise affect the
legal position of any endorsing company, and are not intended to be used against
an endorser in any legal proceeding for any purpose.” (p. 113).
And why should they? If we are operating under the scarcity
model, and the incentive for the tourism industry or host country is to
differentiate its product, ecological and social sustainability become just two
of a vast array of distinguishing features whereby a destination can attract
consumers. To make money you can go
green, or you can serve cheap alcohol and high end call girls. Your call. And since governments cater to business interests,
unless a given activity (say the downwind pollution spewing cement factory in
Boca Chica) has a direct effect on the resorts upwind, or the blaring music
from the public beach restaurants reaches the resort beach to spoil its
tranquility, there is no reason to try and make broad legislation that affects
all development across the board. It
isn’t just that the fox is watching its own chicken coop, for the logic of the
market says that as islands like the Dominican Republic degrade there will be
more and more of a reason for certain resorts, like the exclusive Punta Cana
resort featured in Conde Nast Traveler as one of the most sustainable tourist
destinations on the planet, to continue to up their game, the fox will indeed
ensure that the chickens are healthy. It
is the structural problem of how this logic affects the whole, affects the
wider tourist destination ecosystem, that is the problem.
Competition for the Ecolabels and the independent
certification and accreditation from third parties that give them credence and
value, can ironically lead to a
situation where their value is wholly dependent on there being enough unlabeled
and inadequate operations to cause a significant price differential. The laws of
supply and demand rule all businesses. Ecolabels are defined by Font, 2001 as
‘methods to standardize the promotion of environmental claims by following
compliance to set criteria, generally based on third party, impartial
verification (p 115).” But standardization
and set criteria are diametrically opposed concepts to differentiation and high
quality. There is an assumption that the
reason government regulation works is because businesses supposedly fear the
possibility that “government will step in and increase its own (external and
obligatory) regulations if industry does not regulate itself in a responsible
and credible manner” says Weaver on page 114. “The potential loss of power over
its own affairs is therefore an enormous incentive to adhere to codes of
conduct as well as higher forms of internal and voluntary quality control
(Mason and Mowforth 1996). P. 114.
But something is rotten in the state of Denmark, and the
Dominican Republic and everywhere else for that matter. What happens when we apply the concept of
Walrasian Equilibrium to tourism as L. Dwyer does in “The International
Handbook on the Economics of Tourism” (page 302), and investigate whether the
fundamental interrelationships between sectors are driving distributional
effects on policies for resource allocation as certain tourist destinations go
green? And what happens when we apply Immanuel Wallerstein’s World Systems
Theory which suggests that there is a world economic system in which some
countries benefit precisely because others are exploited? How can we think about Sustainable Tourism if
we apply Andre Gunder Frank’s insights about the 5000 year history of this
torturous equilibrium and its inevitability, creating what he called “The
Development of Underdevelopment” where both are two aspects of the same system
and underdeveloped or unsustainable areas are the direct result of their
relationship with the developed or sustainable areas?
Weaver tells us that the Elements of Success include the
need for sponsors of a given code of
Quality to “make available examples of
tangible practices and objectives” so that best practices may be imitated by
others and bad practices avoided. But if
the value added prospects of a tourism business rely on green innovations then
the best practices become a kind of “intellectual property” which competitive
tourism operators are loath to share with others so they can protect their
brand. Weaver talks about industry
incentives for participation and notes that “A primary reason for the tourism
industry to seek affiliation and certification with ecolables is to demonstrate
external recognition for their sustainability
practices and accomplishments… through the credibility this provides
they are more likely to generate
positive publicity that translates into increased business from green consumers,
leverage to charge a premium price and a reduced likelihood of government intervention.”
He reminds us that “A successful ecolabel is one that is widely recognized and
patronized by consumers and other stakeholders, thereby conferring the bearer with a competitive advantage over
rival products that do NOT possess the ecolabel…(p. 116). “ He tells us that
Buckley in 2002 suggested that a successful ecolabel must have suffiecient
‘guts’ or the substantive criteria that distinguishes products with the ecolabel from those who do
not have it, as well as ‘teeth’ or procedures that ensure the use of the
ecolabel only where it is warranted”.
But when you take World Systems Theory into account, this
sounds problematic. To me it smacks of a
lack of imagination. What happens when
we reach a standard practice state of sustainability and justice, and create a
world where the use of the desired ecolabel is ALWAYS warrented? Are we
suggesting that we don’t believe such a world is possible? Is sustainability really
only some fantasy utopia we can only dream about? What happens to tourism when everyone
everywhere is engaged in best practices? Does the green sector simply vanish
and with it the premium that was the driving incentive in the first place?
Right now this may seem inconceivable to proponents of
ecolabels and certifications who face a daily struggle even getting tourists
and tour operators to be aware they even exist and are vitally concerned with
tourist destinations falling off the decline end of Butler’s S curve. Weaver says on page 125 “A major weakness in
tourism ecolabelling is the continuing lack of consumer recognition, which
reduces the incentive for tourism companies to become involved in such schemes
and thus leads to a second major problem of lackluster corporate participation
levels. “ He cautions against
greenwashing and the ability of companies to “obtain an ecolabel on the basis
of meeting certain (e.g. recycling and energy reduction) while
continuing to engage in activities such
as habitat clearance that are harmful to the environment but not included in
the criteria inventory”. He worries that
“laudable environmental practices may disguise unethical social and cultural
practices” and concludes that “ultimately there is still no widespread belief
or convincing evidence that products with ecolabels are demonstrably more
sustainable than those without, even though Green Globe 21 appears to be
‘pulling ahead of the pack’ through its three-tier award structure that
culminates in the third party certification of an array of relevant indicators.”
The irony is that on the one hand there aren’t enough ecolabels in some areas and on the other there are TOO MANY ecolabels in another while the “actual number of participating companies is still negligible relative to the total potential number of companies and its geographic and sectoral scope” and may be “too ambitious relative to its resources” so that “the scheme therefore has a long way to go before it can be regarded as an effective mechanism for attaining sustainable tourism development within the tourism industry.” P. 125
The irony is that on the one hand there aren’t enough ecolabels in some areas and on the other there are TOO MANY ecolabels in another while the “actual number of participating companies is still negligible relative to the total potential number of companies and its geographic and sectoral scope” and may be “too ambitious relative to its resources” so that “the scheme therefore has a long way to go before it can be regarded as an effective mechanism for attaining sustainable tourism development within the tourism industry.” P. 125
The Mohonk Agreement has set in motion the creation of the
Global Sustainable Tourism Stewardship
Council (STSC) to take a macroscopic approach to all of this, but it still
doesn’t seem to be exploring the perspective of World Systems there and doesn’t
seem to question the zero-sum scarcity model logic that undergirds almost all
Capitalist enterprises. Right now the
concern over the global awards accreditation protocols is that awards for those
practicing sustainability are “good opportunities to recognize and publicize
purported industry leaders and role
models” which would seem movement toward Maloney’s 16% advice that we remessage
and rebrand toward “social proof”, but Weaver also contends that “awards are
concurrently intended to serve as public relations exercises for their
sponsors” with “a strong element of self-interest” that “dilutes their
integrity and is evident in the inclusion of sponsor names in the award titles
and in high profile presentation ceremonies. It is for this reason, and the
added factor that only a limited number of qualifiying products can obtain
awards, that the latter are positioned below ecolables within the quality
control spectrum.”
After a whole chapter listing all the various ecolabelling
and credentialing and quality assurance schemes out there, and decrying the
failure of the systems to yet have their intended effect, Weaver summarizes
saying “they should not be dismissed out of hand, since well-constructed codes
facilitate in a non-threatening way the initial engagement in sustainability
(i.e. a minimalist model). They also provide a common ground for networking and
a basis for identifying suitable indicators, they exercise a moral suasion over
adherents and they help to pre-empt further government regulation if they
actually support sustainable outcomes.”
IF.
The problem, unexplored in the chapter, is the unexplained
yet underlying internal contradictions
of the world capitalist system. When
Weaver says “The Use of the Ecolabel must be restricted to certified tourism
products that are broadly recognized, at least by green tourists, as being
SUPERIOR to uncertified COMPETING Products” and tells us that “THIS RECOGNITION
ALLOWS THE PRODUCT TO COMMAND A PRICE PREMIUM AND HENCE SERVES AS A FINANCIAL
INCENTIVE FOR COMPANIES TO PARTICIPATE IN THE ECOLABEL AS LONG AS ITS
ACQUISITION IS NOT TOO ONEROURS OR
EXPENSIVE A PROCESS” he is tacitly admitting that the “code of conduct” he
described as a “code of ethics” aiming to “influence the attitudes and behavior
of those claiming adherence to it” on page 111 isn’t a code of ethics at
all. It is merely business as usual, no
ethics required. The attitude of the capitalist world system isn’t influenced
in the least, and the behavior is still driven by market share. He states the problem that “it is not at all
clear that ecolabelled products are adequately differentiated from non-ecolabelled
products” rather than the problem that differentiation is arguably got us into
trouble in the first place.
The real question is “why are there any unhealthy, unsustainable and unjust places and behaviors in the first place? Why do we even need ecolabels at all? Shouldn’t SUSTAINABILITY AND JUSTICE BE BUSINESS AS USUAL?
In conclusion, I would like to ask you to imagine a world in which there is nothing special about being green. How would you run your tourism business and make a living on a truly green planet where beautiful, safe, healthy, exciting landscapes surrounded us all, where wild places and charismatic wildlife were everywhere we looked, as they were for most of human history. How would you run your tourism business where every beach was clean and unspoiled and relaxation in nature could be found in everyone’s backyard? Has tourism been on the rise since the industrial revolution and especially post World War II in part because much of the world has become so unlivable and undesirable that people are willing to save up for year just to spend a week or two in places that still look much as they did before the industrial revolution and a few world wars wrecked things everywhere else?
Is sustainable tourism, by operating according to a zero-sum scarcity model, continuing to perpetuate the very underdevelopment it says it seeks to repair. Is it insidiously making the chasm between the few haves who have access to desirable destinations and other 84% who don’t larger?
What do you think?
The real question is “why are there any unhealthy, unsustainable and unjust places and behaviors in the first place? Why do we even need ecolabels at all? Shouldn’t SUSTAINABILITY AND JUSTICE BE BUSINESS AS USUAL?
In conclusion, I would like to ask you to imagine a world in which there is nothing special about being green. How would you run your tourism business and make a living on a truly green planet where beautiful, safe, healthy, exciting landscapes surrounded us all, where wild places and charismatic wildlife were everywhere we looked, as they were for most of human history. How would you run your tourism business where every beach was clean and unspoiled and relaxation in nature could be found in everyone’s backyard? Has tourism been on the rise since the industrial revolution and especially post World War II in part because much of the world has become so unlivable and undesirable that people are willing to save up for year just to spend a week or two in places that still look much as they did before the industrial revolution and a few world wars wrecked things everywhere else?
Is sustainable tourism, by operating according to a zero-sum scarcity model, continuing to perpetuate the very underdevelopment it says it seeks to repair. Is it insidiously making the chasm between the few haves who have access to desirable destinations and other 84% who don’t larger?
What do you think?
And… what are you going to do about it?
No comments:
Post a Comment